Economic Instruments in Environmental Protection in Denmark 6. Effluent taxes6. Effluent taxes
|
Space heating |
Heavy process |
Light process |
Energy used to heat the following types of rooms: production, stock, sale, offices, hotel rooms, and refreshment rooms. |
Activities where the production is depended on a high energy consumption. An appendix to the law on CO2 taxation specifies what kind of activities are considered to be heavy process (35 processes all in all). |
Energy consumption in all other processes, i.e. office machines, machines in general, etc. |
The tax is implemented gradually, providing a certain adjustment time for the enterprises. Table 6.1 shows an overview of the taxes and the scheme for their phase-in.
Table 6.1
CO2 tax rates 1995-2000 for different categorises of energy use
(DKK per ton CO2)
Use category |
1995 |
1996 |
1997 |
1998 |
1999 |
2000 |
Households |
100 |
100 |
100 |
100 |
100 |
100 |
Space heating (industry)* |
0 |
100 |
100 |
100 |
100 |
100 |
Light process with agreement |
50 |
50 |
50 |
50 |
58 |
68 |
Heavy process with agreement |
>0 |
3 |
3 |
3 |
3 |
3 |
The table demonstrates that:
The tax rate for energy used for space heating in industry has been at the full rate of DKK 100 per ton since the introduction in 1996. | |
The CO2 tax rates for light and heavy processes increase during the whole period 1995-2000. However, the rate for heavy processes with agreement remains stable on a lower level. |
The table also illustrates that the full tax rate of 100 DKK per ton of CO2 only applies in two cases: 1) to households; and 2) for energy used for space heating and hot water in industry.
Enterprises are entitled to enter an agreement if they meet one of two criteria:
The tax is levied on the fuels that are used in energy production. It is collected through the same mechanisms as the traditional energy taxes. This mechanism is described in section 5.1.
Two bodies are primarily involved in the implementation of the CO2-tax (including also the refund mechanisms) and the corresponding system of agreements. The bodies involved are the regional departments of Customs and Excise, and the Energy Agency. The roles and responsibilities of these two authorities are illustrated in Table 6.2.
Table 6.2
The CO2 tax and associated agreement scheme. Roles and
responsibilities of the involved authorities.
The Department of Customs and Excise (and regional offices) |
The Energy Agency (The Ministry of Environment and Energy) |
||||
|
|
||||
|
|
Tax collection
All enterprises must install measurement equipment to measure the energy use within the three categories (space heating, heavy, and light process). They have a good incentive to comply with this obligation, because all non-specified energy consumption is considered as space heating. Hence, it is liable to the highest CO2 tax and energy tax.
The enterprises report on the consumption of energy to the Department of Customs and Excise following their VAT payments, and in connection with their VAT reporting. The accounts constitute the basis for calculating the amount of refund that the enterprise is entitled to. If there are doubts about the accuracy of the accounts, the department is entitled and obligated to investigate this further.
The tax authorities also control whether the enterprises have installed the correct measurement equipment, and monitor that enterprises pay according to the actual consumption of energy.
Figure 6.2
Use categories and tax rates by year 2000
(scan the print)
Enterprises that submit incorrect information, or suppress relevant information can be fined. However, conflicts are first sought to be solved through negotiations.
Contracting of agreements
The entry of an agreement entitles an enterprise for a tax reduction, and obliges it to undertake certain energy saving actions. The agreements are entered between the Energy Agency on one hand, and either the single enterprise or a branch organisation on the other.
The specific contents of an agreement (i.e. the obligations of the enterprise) are established through negotiations with the Energy Agency. Prior to these negotiations, the enterprise must:
carry out an energy audit;
make a report on its energy management; and
The above constitute inputs into the subsequent negotiations with the Energy Agency. The negotiations will result in decisions on the specific actions that the enterprise must carry out, in order to be entitled to the tax deduction. An action plan is an important outcome of the negotiations.
The CO2 package will be fully implemented in 2000. By that time, it is estimated that the tax revenue from trade and industry will be close to DKK 2.1 billion. From the 1995 tax, it is expected that the revenue will amount to MDKK 800-1,000. The remaining MDKK 1,000 will be fully recycled to industry and trade, with the exception of a small amount to be used to cover administrative costs.
Two mechanisms have been established to accomplish a recycling scheme that supports the intentions of the CO2 package:
1. financial support to new investment in
enterprises; and
2. lowering of labour costs.
Table 6.3
The expected CO2-tax revenue for 1999 divided on main sources
(MDKK)
Households |
Oil used to land transportation |
Energy consumed |
Other |
2,500 |
400 |
1,700 |
25 |
Source: Finanslov for finansåret 1999
The CO2-tax is an example of a case where conflicting concerns must be balanced to reach an acceptable outcome for the parties involved, and which to a reasonable extent, targets the environmental objectives.
On one hand, substantial tax reductions are awarded to industry. This significantly weakens the environmental accomplishments of the tax. On the other hand, industrys competitiveness could be substantially hampered if the industry was imposed with the full tax. The resulting design of the tax, together with the recycling scheme, presents a compromise between these conflicting concerns.
The fact that electricity production is taxed at the output level does not, per se, provide an incentive to reduce CO2 emissions, because it does not provide an incentive to switch to fuels that contain less CO2. However, the CO2 tax on electricity production should be seen in conjunction with the subsidisation scheme that is described in chapter 11. This scheme leads to tax neutrality for natural gas, and to a factual reduction in the case of renewable energy sources.
Although the CO2 tax is 100 DKK/ton the effective taxation of CO2 is much larger. This is, because the effects from the energy taxes on price structures are quite similar with regard to CO2.
The linkage of the CO2 tax to the agreement scheme supports its innovative effects.
Sulphur emissions result from the burning of fuels with a high content of sulphur like oil and coal.
In accordance with international agreements, Denmark is obligated to reduce its emission so that it by year 2000 correspond to no more than 80% of the 1980 level. Several measures are applied to achieve this reduction. These measures include, among others: the use of emission quotas for power plants; mandatory desulphurisation units in new power plants; and limit values for the sulphur content in fuels.
Emissions have declined significantly during the 1980s. However, it became apparent in 1994 that additional measures were needed if the 80% reduction target was to be met. This spurred interest in the potentials of economic instruments. Consequently, the tax on SO2 (sulphur) went into force on January 1, 1996.
The purpose of the tax is to contribute to reducing Danish SO2 emissions, and thereby to contribute to achieving the 80% reduction target. The SO2 tax may be considered as a green tax in the sense that it has been developed solely to achieve an environmental target. Specifically, the tax is expected to lead to an emissions decline in the range of 25,000-30,000 tons of SO2. This will result in an emission level by the year 2000 of about 73,500 tons, compared with the 1980 level of about 100,000 tons.
The following four mechanisms are expected to lead to this reduction. The exact effects are, however, somewhat uncertain. More accurate estimates would require in-depth studies on the cost structures and options inherent in each of the four mechanisms:
The tax may lead to reductions in the overall energy use. This effect is further reinforced by the fact that there is a positive correlation between the sulphur content and the CO2 content of fuels.
The tax is recycled to industry until the year 2000. During that period, taxes are only imposed on sulphur contents above specific lower limit values. The limit values are shown in Table 6.4[3]. For very energy intensive coal-based enterprises, there is a scheme for further deductions in general terms. This implies that the enterprises are entitled to deductions for all sulphur contents below 0.2 (the 1996 limit value). Hence, these enterprises are liable to a tax which continues to apply for sulphur content above 0.2, whereas other enterprises are liable to taxes that apply to steadily lower sulphur content (as shown in Table 6.4)
To be entitled to this further relief, which applies also after year 2000, the enterprise must, however, comply with three conditions: 1) the fuel must be applied in processes that are defined by law as heavy processes; 2) the enterprise must have entered an agreement with the Energy Agency on energy efficiency issues; and 3) the enterprise should have constructed or renovated its boiler or oven for an amount of at least 10 MDKK during the last twenty years.
Table 6.4
Limit values for deductions in liable SO2 taxes
Year |
1996 |
1997 |
1998 |
1999 |
2000 |
Kg SO2/GJ |
0.20 |
0.15 |
0.10 |
0.05 |
0 |
The SO2 tax differs from other environmental taxes in the sense that it contains an optional feature. Industry liable to the tax may thus choose between two options for being levied by the tax. The provision of this option is motivated by the fact that it is possible to clean flue gas, thereby, it is technically possible to actually remove the sulphur. Industry is provided with a choice between:
Moreover, the following features apply to the SO2 tax:
The tax only applies to fuels with a sulphur content above 0.05% (in 1999). This applies to both optional tax bases. Therefore, a tax of zero applies to petrol, kerosene, and light diesel; | |
Oil energy products used for electricity production are not liable to the tax until 2000. The rationale for this lies in concerns over competitiveness vis-à-vis electricity production in Germany, Norway, and Sweden. Instead, a specific electricity tax is implemented, which will eventually take the same effect. From year 2000, however, use of energy for electricity production will become liable to a tax based on realised emissions; and | |
Sea-borne carriage and air transport are both exempted from the tax. |
The tax has been phased in gradually during the period of 1996-1999. Tax levels increase gradually over this period, and the tax will take its full effect by the year 2000.
Table 6.5
The two options for the SO2 tax
Features |
Tax on sulphur in fuels |
Tax on SO2
|
Tax base |
The amount of sulphur in the fossil fuels (oil, coal, natural gas) and other fuels (wood, straw, waste) The exact tax for each fuel is calculated on the basis of a conversion table, which specifies the sulphur content in each fuel |
The actual emission of sulphur from the enterprise as metered by the enterprises |
Tax level |
DKK 20 per kg sulphur |
DKK 10 per kg sulphur dioxide |
Specific requirements |
Enterprises need to have a permission to pay the tax as a product tax. To obtain a permission the enterprises must e.g. have installed appropriate metering equipment |
The tax is calculated and paid by the oil companies and the coal importers, as well as other importers and producers. The number of entities liable to the tax is quite small. The oil companies and the coal importers must register with the Department of Customs and Excise. The obligation to register applies to both optional tax bases.
In some cases, plants have their fuels delivered directly. In these cases, the tax is not due until the actual use of the fuels has taken place. The plants must specify the use of each fuel. The tax is calculated according to standard values for the sulphur content in the different fuels.
The registered enterprises pay the tax to the Department of Customs and Excise. The enterprises must keep track of the amount of dutiable products that has either left the enterprises, or which they have consumed.
The taxation authorities may ultimately withdraw the registration of an enterprise in the case of delayed, omitted, or wrong tax payments. Other possible sanctions include the imposition of rent payments and fines.
The national taxation authorities are entitled to perform unannounced inspections of the enterprises to check, for example, the relevant accounts and the measurement systems applied.
The revenue from the SO2 tax is fairly small, but continues, however, to increase during the phase-in period. The tax is expected to generate revenues in the order of MDKK 575 in 1999[4], whereas it was MDKK 375 in 1998[5]. In the first year of operation (1996), the tax generated revenues of MDKK 296.5.
The SO2 tax applies similarly to households and industry with a uniform rate of DKK 20 per kilo of SO2. However, industry is awarded some reductions as described above.
The optional approach where plants may choose to be levied an emission tax, rather than a product tax, represents a move towards a stronger relation between the tax and the environmental issue to be tackled. In principle, the emissions tax would allow more flexibility to the individual plant. This follows from the fact that the emissions tax allows the plant in question to apply the most efficient combination of fuel switches, use of fuels with lower sulphur content, and end-of-pipe solutions. By contrast, the product tax does not provide an incentive to also consider the last option.
Administratively, the tax is closely linked to existing systems and procedures, therefore, limiting the administrative costs. However, the emissions tax is a fairly new type of tax. Its performance will, therefore be monitored in order to identify possible needs for changes in its design.
All in all, experience indicates that emissions have declined while the tax has been in effect.
The tax on waste and raw materials has been in force since January 1, 1990. Since then, revisions have been undertaken and the rates applied have increased. Originally, the tax replaced an administrative charge that entered into force in 1987. The tax was last revised in 1997.
The tax applies to the extraction and import of raw materials, and to waste. This is, because of the need to define in a common law, the distinction between recovered waste and raw materials.
The purpose of the tax is to reduce resource use and to support the Danish waste hierarchy. The Danish waste hierarchy is in line with the EU priorities. It emphasises first, and foremost, recovery and recycling. Further, incineration with heat recovery and a minimum of 10% electricity production is preferred over other incineration which is again preferred over depositing. The Danish waste hierarchy also emphasises the need to reduce resource use. Danish priorities are:
1. prevention;
2. recovery and recycling;
3. incineration with CHP production;
4. other incineration; and
5. final disposal.
Waste management is the responsibility of the municipalities. The municipalities are obligated to establish and operate municipal waste companies, and to take care of the collection of municipal waste. To fulfil this obligation, waste companies are established. In some cases the waste companies are inter-municipal where one or more neighbouring municipalities join together to solve this task.
The waste tax provides these companies with an incentive to recover as much waste as possible (recovered waste is liable to a tax rate of 0). The tax further favours incineration to disposal. Consequently, there is incentive to establish incineration (with heat recovery and preferably also with power production) facilities.
The tax is fully recovered at the end user level. This means that ultimately industry and households come to pay the tax. As opposed to many other economic instruments in environmental protection in Denmark, the waste tax thus applies 100% to industry. Consequently, industry has an incentive to minimise its waste production, and to sort the waste according to the categories for tax differentiation. Households on the other hand do not, in most cases, pay in full accordance with the specific amounts of waste they produce.
The tax applies to raw materials and waste delivered to a waste plant. Hazardous waste destined for incineration is exempted from the tax. Enterprises that extract and/or import raw materials are liable to the raw materials tax.
Table 6.6
Waste taxes (excluding sludge). 1996-1998. DKK/kg
Waste type |
1996 |
1997 |
1998 |
Waste for landfills |
195 |
335 |
375 |
Incineration with complete or minimum (in the case of CHP plants) 10% power production |
160 |
210 |
280 |
Other incineration |
160 |
260 |
330 |
Recovered waste |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Raw materials that are used in production are taxed with a rate of 5 DKK/m3. In the case of imported semi-final or final products that contain the raw materials, a comparable tax is calculated and levied. The raw materials tax does not apply to materials that are used for beach nourishment or the beneficial use of dredged material.
If, for a specific enterprise, the amount of extracted or imported raw materials is less than 200 m3/year, its liability to the tax is cancelled.
Sludge is liable to the tax structure described in Table 6.6. Legislation stipulates a specific method for converting the amounts into applicable quantities. The inclusion of sludge, provides an incentive to use as much sludge as possible for productive purposes. This could, for example, be as fertiliser.
Facilities that deposit waste products from the combined production of heat and power (CHP) are exempted from the tax. The recent revision also excluded deposited waste from heat and power production based on biomass. The waste tax has thus been revised to contribute to fulfil the CO2 emissions reductions target, because the revision has removed the previous preferential position of the coal-based CHPs.
Producers or importers of raw materials must register with the Department of Customs and Excise. Further, all waste plants must register. The obligation to register also applies to plants that incinerate sludge solely (sewage treatment plants), importers of waste, and enterprises that dispose of, or incinerate waste by themselves.
Enterprises that sell raw materials, either unprocessed, or simply processed (in terms of, for example, crushing) must keep accounts of their sales.
The tax is collected on a quarterly basis where registered enterprises calculate the chargeable amounts. The Department of Customs and Excise is in charge of control. Possible sanctions include fines and the ultimate withdrawal of registration.
All waste is weighed upon delivery to a waste treatment plant. The registered weight of the waste constitutes the basis for the calculation of the tax. The tax is paid to the waste treatment plant in question upon the delivery of the waste.
The applied tax rate and the total tax that have been paid, should be clearly identifiable on the weight sheets.
Initially, the waste tax was only 40 DKK/ton. Over time it has been substantially increased. The present levels range between 210 and 335 DKK/ton; an increase of between 400% and 700%. Furthermore, tax differentiation has been added to the scheme. The latest revision included a new differentiation between incineration plants that produce power and heat, and plants that only recover heat. As a result of the steady increases in the tax rates, revenues from the tax have increased substantially over the years.
Table 6.6
Revenue from the waste tax and from the tax on raw materials. MDKK. 1996-1998
Year/tax type |
Waste tax |
Raw materials tax |
1996 |
601 |
135 |
1997 |
867 |
145 |
1998 |
889 |
157 |
1999 |
1,150 |
160 |
Source: Finanslov for finansåret 1999 and Statsregnskab for finansåret 1998
Developments since 1993 indicate that that waste volumes have remained stable, or have even increased slightly. By contrast, waste volumes declined during the late 1980s and the early 1990s. Positive economic developments in Denmark during the last five years, presumably explain the fact that waste volumes have not declined during this time. Evidence from many countries suggests a strong positive correlation between waste production and economic developments.
From 1987 to 1996, there was a 26% reduction in the amounts of waste delivered to municipal waste treatment plants. Deliveries to smaller landfills and private waste sites declined by 39 % from 1990 to 1996. The main reason for the latter is mainly, that increasing amounts of waste are delivered to the municipal plants at the expense of the smaller sites and the private ones. Waste recovery plants outside the municipal ones have also received increasing amounts of waste.
The current structure of the waste tax strongly encourages recycling and reuse, and provides a fairly strong incentive to minimise waste production. Furthermore, the structure is in accordance with the priorities of Danish waste management:
prevention; | |
recovery and recycling; | |
incineration with CHP production; | |
other incineration; and | |
final disposal. |
It should be noted that almost all incineration in Denmark is combined with heat recovery. The main motivation being that heat recovery is a precondition for the economy of the incineration plant.
The relatively high tax rates and the tax structure thus support the Danish waste priorities. The incentive to minimise waste production and to recover and recycle as much as possible, is further reinforced by other environmental taxes, such as the tax on certain retail containers, and the tax on disposable tableware. The priority of incineration of waste is in accordance with EU priorities and the tax system supports this hierarchy.
While providing a fairly strong economic incentive to act according to the above priorities, the high tax rates also provide an incentive for evasion. Consequently, a key parameter in the efficiency of the tax is the extent to which evasion can be avoided. In this regard, the Danish waste management system has become fairly efficient. The efficiency of the system is further supported by a rather high degree of self-discipline, supported by public opinion. Companies that seek to avoid the tax by means of illegal disposal of waste, will, if discovered, experience strong negative public attention with a consequent loss of goodwill and sales.
The exception of hazardous waste (destined for incineration) from the tax, serves to ensure that all hazardous waste is incinerated properly.
The waste tax and the tax on raw materials, to some extent, affect the competitiveness of Danish industry.
The new tax rates of 1997 were envisaged to lead to an increase in the total revenue in the order of 210 MDKK if the waste amounts would remain unchanged. About 130 MDKK would come from households, and the remaining 80 MDKK from businesses (industry, construction, and other businesses).
The tax is not earmarked. The revenue thus enters the general budget. However, there are subsidy schemes to support initiatives that aim to increase waste recovery and recycling, and to reduce waste production.
Table 6.7
Revenue changes caused by 1997 tax increases. The waste tax.
Tax category |
Amount of waste |
Total tax revenue |
Change |
Sludge for incineration |
150 |
35 |
- |
Incinerated waste with CHP production |
1,600 |
335 |
80 |
Other incinerated waste |
350 |
90 |
15 |
Waste in landfills |
1,600 |
536 |
80 |
Total |
210 |
Most sewage is cleaned at common (typically public) sewage treatment plants before it is discharged into watercourses, seas, and lakes. Further, smaller amounts are discharged from: industrial enterprises that have their own discharge system (with a discharge permit); sparsely built-up areas with no sewerage systems; and fish farms.
Sewage discharge and treatment are fully financed by the dischargers (users of the system), and has been so since 1989. Prior to entry into force of the tax, there was no payment associated with the environmental pressure which discharged treated sewage imposed on fresh and marine waters.
The tax is a result of the 1994 tax reform. It has been in effect since 1997. The tax is designed to take account of the quantities of polluting substances in the discharged sewage:
nitrogen; | |
phosphorus; and | |
organic substances. |
The purpose of the tax is to reduce the amount of polluting substances in the discharged treated sewage. Reductions may be achieved inter alia through:
reduced discharges of sewage from households and industries; | |
reduced leakage from drain pipes and sewers; | |
optimisation of treatment processes; and | |
connection to sewer systems for sparsely built-up areas that were not previously connected. |
The tax aims to provide an incentive to undertake the above actions when the associated costs do not exceed the tax.
The tax further aims to contribute to the lowering of income taxes by means of taxing environmental goods and the use of natural resources.
The tax is highly complex in its design. Therefore, the below description does not aim to be fully exhaustive, but rather it aims to identify and describe the main features of the tax base.
Liable entities
Liable to the tax are:
sewage treatment plants;
industrial dischargers; and
There are, however, a number of exceptions and modifications to this. They are primarily motivated in concerns over competitiveness and sectoral distributional effects. Consequently, the tax has been designed so that certain particularly affected industries are either excluded from, or in most cases, subject to reduced payments.
Table 6.8
Sewage tax levels. 1997 and 1998. DKK/kg
Substance |
1997 |
1998 |
Nitrogen (tot-n) |
10 |
20 |
Phosphorus (tot-p) |
55 |
110 |
Organic substances (BI5) |
5,5 |
11 |
Tax base
The basis for calculating the tax, is the multiple of the amount of discharged treated sewage and the measured concentrations (content) of the above substances in the discharged treated sewage.
The amounts of discharged treated sewage may be calculated directly through the use of meters. The use of meters is mandatory for; 1) units where the discharge permit includes an obligation to measure the discharged amounts of water; and 2) individual discharges where the annual discharge exceeds 50,000 m3.
In other cases, the discharged amounts may be assessed based on the water consumption of the connected properties. This can be based on either metered consumption, or estimated consumption following the rules for estimation that apply to user fees (also in the cases where user fee schemes do not apply).
For the calculation of the concentrations, the system distinguishes between the following treatment plants:
treatment plants where 15% or more of the sewage to be treated comes from households; and | |
treatment plants where less than 15% of the sewage to be treated comes from households. |
In the former case, there are two alternatives. The concentrations may either be measured, or the tax can be calculated using certain standard rates. In the latter case, the standard rates vary according to the treatment technology and processes applied. The rates vary between DKK 0.50/m3 and DKK 1.90 DKK/m3 for various specified treatment facilities and methods. In other cases, the standard rate is 3.80 DKK/m3.
When more than 85% of the sewage comes from industry, the calculation of the tax is based on actual measurements. There is one exception to this. Plants that discharge less than 50,000 m3 of treated sewage per year have the option of applying the standard rate of 3.80 DKK/m3.
Exceptions
Among the most important exemptions from and modifications to the tax are:
The tax is collected from the liable entities (sewage treatment plants; industrial dischargers with their own discharge permit; and units located in sparsely built-up areas which are not connected to sewer systems).
Liable entities must register with the national Customs and Tax authorities, and they obtain a certificate in proof of the registration. There are a few exceptions from this rule, and in these cases, the tax is paid to the municipal authorities who will then settle with the Customs and Tax authorities.
The tax is calculated and collected on a quarterly basis from all the registered dischargers. They are obligated to keep records in proof of both the measurements of concentrations and the basis for the estimated amounts of discharged water.
In the case of exemptions and modifications, such as those listed in section , the registered dischargers shall not pay the tax for which the enterprise in question is entitled to a refund. This means that part of the tax is settled directly by the enterprise in question and the Customs and Tax authorities.
The total revenue from the tax was MDKK 273 in 1998[6], and it is expected to be MDKK 275 in 1999[7].
Table 6.9 compares the expected and the realised revenue from the tax in 1997 and 1998. It should be noted that the tax entered into force on January 1, 1997. The rates that were applied in 1997 were half of those applied in 1998.
The table mentions the Action Plan for the Aquatic Environment. This is a comprehensive plan to improve the aquatic environment. The plan is briefly described in chapter 2. The plan, among other things, imposes environmental requirements onto sewage treatment plants, and it specifically emphasises the need to reduce emissions of nitrogen, phosphorus, and BI5.
The table illustrates that the realised revenue falls short of the expected revenue. This may indicate that quantities are less than expected or that the quality of the discharged water may be better than anticipated.
Table 6.9
Comparison of expected and realised revenue from the waste water tax
Expected revenue at |
Expected revenue at implementation assuming achievement of the objectives of action plan for the aquatic environment |
Actual |
225-300 |
185-245 |
140 |
525-600 |
425-490 |
273 |
Source: Lovforslaget
The exceptions and rules for tax reductions for specifically affected industries are motivated in concerns over competitiveness and difficulties in measurements (in the case of fish farming). The latter sector is, however, subject to numerous other regulations that seek to control its environmental pressure.
The tax is an effluent tax, and as such, it is more difficult to administer and control than most product taxes. It is not possible to measure exactly how many polluting substances are discharged into the environment. The tax authorities need to exercise control of tax payments by making samples. Apart from the samples, the control is based on the treatment plants self-reporting of the amount of polluting substances to the tax authorities.
The section draws on different newsletters from the Department of Customs and Excise and interviews with representatives of the Environmental Protection Agency, the Energy Agency, and representatives for the regional Customs and Excise offices.
[Front page] [Contents] [Previous] [Next] [Top] |